Iii основы реферирования и аннотирования. Практические рекомендации
Вид материала | Методические рекомендации |
СодержаниеAre the poor different ? Behind the times |
- Вопрос: Теория и практика реферирования, 8.08kb.
- Обучение реферированию на уроках английского языка дубинина Т. Г. Красноярский государственный, 178.2kb.
- Аннотация примерной программы учебной дисциплины Иностранный язык Цели и задачи дисциплины, 2303.53kb.
- Аннотация примерной программы учебной дисциплины Иностранный язык Цели и задачи дисциплины, 2532.37kb.
- Практические рекомендации 3-е издание, переработанное и дополненное Домодедово 2007, 710.08kb.
- Методические указания и практические рекомендации по прохождению, 964.89kb.
- Практические рекомендации по выбору типовой модели системы управления качеством образования, 825.59kb.
- Практические рекомендации по выбору типовой модели системы управления качеством образования, 869.13kb.
- Т. В. Черткова Бухгалтерский учет, Основы бухгалтерского учета, Практические основы, 29.47kb.
- Iii. Продукия, ее особенности 6 III описание продукции 6 III применяемые технологии, 2464.73kb.
Text B.
1. Переведите следующий текст:
ARE THE POOR DIFFERENT ?
Developing countries have their own branch of economics. It is far from obvious that they need it.
Michel Camdessus, the managing director of the IMF, calls it the “silent revolution”. Wall Street financiers talk of the “emerging market era”. Other commentators refer more sourly to the “triumph of free-market economics”. They are all describing the same phenomenon: the dramatic shift in economic policy that has swept the developing world in the past few years.
The individual prescriptions are, by now, familiar: dismantle trade barriers, tighten fiscal policy, privatise state-owned firms, attack inflation, and so forth. Underlying them all, however, is an implicit assumption that the basic premises of prudent economic management are the same whether you are in Brazil, Benin or Belgium.
But is this assumption right? Three decades ago most economists would have answered, No. Spawned by the end of the colonial era in the 1950s and 1960s, a whole branch of economic theory grew up around the question of how to promote economic development in poor countries. The proposition on which “development economics” was built was that poor countries were intrinsically different from rich ones, and so needed their own set of economic models.
Some development economists argued, for instance, that the self-interested, rational individual (the basic actor in most economists’ models since Adam Smith’s time), did not exist in “traditional” tribal societies. And they claimed that because many poor countries had large agricultural populations and were often dependent on a few commodity exports for foreign-exchange earnings, economic policies that suited rich nations would not be appropriate for them.
With hindsight, much of this was misguided, and policies based on it had disastrous effects. Development economists believed that the state had to play a big role in fostering modernisation. But this led to huge, corrupt and inefficient bureaucracies, massive budget deficits and, indirectly, to rampant inflation. Much of the “silent revolution” of the past decade has consisted of correcting these mistakes.
So what, if anything, is left of development economics? Pierre-Richard Agenor, an economist at the IMF, argues that while the basic microeconomic assumptions about how people behave are similar for all countries, developing economies still differ “structurally” from rich ones, and therefore demand different models.
To support their case, the author lists the traits that he reckons “typical” developing countries still share. They tend to be more open than richer ones (that is to say, trade contributes a bigger fraction of national income), and to depend more on foreign capital. They tend to have fixed exchange rates and, often, exchange controls. Their financial markets are rudimentary and often distorted by heavy government regulation. The public sector plays a bigger role than in rich countries, particularly in directing the pattern of investment.
One obvious difficulty with this approach is that there is, in fact, no such thing as a “typical” developing country. Remember that the official “developing world” includes the fast-growing Asian tigers, the volatile economies of Latin America and the poorest nations in Africa. While some countries may share a number of the traits that the authors outline, few share them all.
A second objection is that many of the “structural differences” are, in fact, the relics of old policies inspired bydevelopment economics. Exchange controls are an example. As countries begin their reform process, these have been quickly lifted. Ditto for some of the restrictions on local financial markets.
Moreover, other apparent differences such as the importance of trade and capital flows in emerging markets - are nothing of the sort. They apply equally to many industrialised countries. This does have an implication for macroeconomics, but for the field in general, not just for the poor world. For simplicity’s sake, most traditional mainstream macroeconomic models assumed that an economy was closed (ie, that it had no relations with the rest of the world). In an increasingly integrated global economy, this assumption makes little sense. Macroeconomics, in rich and poor countries alike, must take the rest of the world into account.
That said, certain specific policy issues do seem to matter more in developing countries than in rich ones. Few developed countries, for example, have to contend with inflation rates of 20-30% a year; none has to worry about taming hyperinflation. In poorer countries, this problem is still high on the economic-policy agenda. In less developed economies, policymakers have a smaller range of financial tools at their disposal. Conducting monetary policy in an African country where domestic bond markets barely exist is clearly different from influencing interest rates in, say, France.
Behind the times
In the early 1990’s stabilising high inflation and the aftermath of the 1980s debt crisis preoccupied many goverments.
Nowadays, the problems of coping with rapid swings in capital flows are more pressing - a fact that was highlighted by Mexico’s financial crisis, 1998. As poor countries continue to free their markets and to curb the role of the state, many of the remaining “structural differences” with rich ones will disappear. Sooner rather than later, there will only be two types of macroeconomic policy: good and bad.
VOCABULARY
1. emerging markets | развивающиеся рынки |
2. emerging countries | страны с развивающимися рыночными отношениями (часто новые индустриальные страны) |
3. development economics | экономическая теория развития |
4. a fraction of national income | доля (часть) национального дохода |
5. trait(s) | характерные черты |
6. macroeconomics | макроэкономическая теория |
7. taming hyperinflation | обуздание гиперинфляции |
2. Напишите аннотацию данного текста.